This is a final version submitted for publication. Minor editorial changes may have subsequently been made.
How much would you be willing to pay to save the snow leopard from extinction?
It may surprise you to know that asking questions like this is one of the
best ways economists have for working out what the environment is worth. The
spontaneous answer you and others give to such a question may determine whether
a forest is protected. The whole project of integrating environmental and
economic goals seems to depend on one proposition: that it is possible and
desirable to attach monetary values to separate parts of the environment.
This proposition is being promoted by a group of economists, who call themselves
environmental economists. Responding to environmental crises that have emerged
in recent years they have adapted traditional economic models and theories
to take account of the environment. They believe that giving the environment
a monetary value is the only way to ensure that decision-makers in government
and business consider the environment when they made their decisions.
Many of these environmental economists come from the neoclassical school of
economics, a branch of economics that believes the 'free market' is the best
way of organising society. They are searching for ways of adjusting the market
system because they recognise that it has failed to protect the environment.
For example, many firms who sell their products in the market cause environmental
damage that neither they nor their customers pay for. They can pollute the
air or the waterways without paying for the damage. Other firms dig up resources
and cut down trees without paying for the loss of environmental amenity and
habitat that result. Each firm considers only its own profits and costs. Environmental
costs seldom get a look in. They are external to the company account books.
Economists call these costs "externalities".
These environmental economists of the neoclassical school argue that the market
would protect the environment if everyone had to take account of these "externalities"
or environmental costs. And what is the best way to do that? By putting a
price on the environment. They say that unless the environment is valued in
monetary terms it will be neglected. Managers and politicians are used to
dealing with monetary values and can more easily relate to them. For instance,
the benefits from preserving a wetland can be compared with the benefits of
filling it in and building a housing estate if each option is given a monetary
value.
Once the various parts of the environment are given a price then all sorts
of decisions are affected. National accounts can be adjusted to take account
of environmental resources lost in the process of generating wealth. In this
way measures such as GNP and GDP will give a better indication of the true
wealth of a nation. As a result, the theory goes, governments will find that
economic development that destroys the environment does not improve GNP so
they will be less likely to encourage it.
Similarly cost-benefit analyses used to decide whether government projects
should go ahead can include quantified environmental costs and this means
that governments will give more weight to environmental considerations when
they decide if the project should go ahead. If the profits from the project
will be less than the cosy of the environmental losses then the project is
unlikely to be given approval.
Environmental taxes and charges can be used to ensure that private firms pay
the costs of the environmental damage that they cause. This is supposed to
provide an incentive for them to reduce that damage. For example a company
that has to pay a charge to put toxic waste into a river may work out that
it can save money by treating its wastes before putting them in the river.
If it decides not to do this then it has to pay the full charge. In this way
the cost of the pollution is incorporated into the price of its products.
Consumers then have the choice of paying the extra. Alternatively they can
buy a different product that is cheaper because it causes less environmental
damage. (Assuming such alternatives are available!)
In all these ways, putting a price on the environment is a way of ensuring
that the cost of environmental damage is considered by governments, firms
and individual consumers when they make their decisions. The decision is still
theirs, which is why it is attractive to free market advocates, but the balance
has been shifted in favour of the environment. But is this enough to protect
the environment for future generations?
One of the first problems is whether the price the economist puts on the environment
reflects its true value. Do we have enough information to know the real value
of species and ecosystems? Our society is ignorant of most species that exist,
the role they play in their ecosystems, how they interact, and the use or
value they might be to humans now and in the future. "How do we deal
with values of organisms whose very existence escapes our notice?" David
Ehrenfeld, a US professor of biology, asks. "What sort of value do we
assign to the loss to the community when a whole generation of its children
can never experience the streams in their environment as amenities?"
Bryan Norton compares the reasoning of economists to hospital administrators
trying to work out which parts of a life-support system can be disconnected
and sold to raise money for the hospital. They do not really know which part
is necessary for the continued operation of the support system, and have to
guess which parts will not be missed. "It is one thing to treat the valuation
of biodiversity as a guessing game or as a set of very interesting theoretical
problems in welfare economics. It is quite another thing to suggest that the
guesses we make are to be the basis of decision making that will affect the
functioning of the ecosystems on which we and our children will depend for
life."
Yet most of the methods used by economists in practice do not consider the
value of the environment in terms of its role and functioning as a life support
system. Rather they value the environment as a commodity whose market value
can be assessed by finding out the public's willingness to pay to preserve
it. This is done directly through surveys where a selection of people is asked
what they would pay to protect, for example, a particular area of forest.
The responses are averaged and totaled up for the whole community so that
a final dollar amount for the forest is arrived at. Alternatively willingness
to pay is calculated indirectly. For example the value of clean air might
be arrived at by estimating how much extra people actually pay for homes in
an unpolluted area.
People's willingness to pay is of course intimately linked with their ability
to pay or their incomes. Affluent people are more willing to pay large sums
of money for what they want because they are able to pay large amounts. Does
this mean that they value their local environment more than poorer people
value theirs? Clearly methods that depend on willingness to pay underrate
the values of people with low incomes. This was most evident recently when
environmental economist David Pearce and his colleagues used this method to
value lives and found that the lives of people living in affluent countries
were worth up to 15 times the lives of those living in poor countries because
people in poorer countries were less willing to pay large amounts of money
to avoid risk of death.
The market is a system that advantages those most able to pay. So relying
on a market system to protect the environment will inevitably disadvantage
the poor. Siting a dirty industry in an already dirty area or an area where
property values are depressed will be less costly, according to the economists,
than siting it in an affluent low-pollution area because the costs of pollution,
if measured in terms of decline in property values, will be lower.
Just because the quantified benefits of an action outweigh the costs, it does
not mean that the decision is morally correct or politically acceptable. For
example, child labour or slavery would be considered immoral even if the economic
advantages to the whole society outweighed the costs to some individuals.
Pricing mechanisms and markets tend to ignore distributional issues such as
who gets the benefits and who bears the costs. Economists assume the society
as a whole is better off if total benefits outweigh total costs, even if a
small group of people gets the benefits and a whole community suffers the
costs.
Judging the value of the environment by how much today's generation is willing
to pay not only discriminates against future generations and the poor. It
also suggests that the only value that nature has is in terms of its usefulness
to humans. Deep ecologists would argue that this is unacceptable and arrogant.
It denies other living things any intrinsic value, that is any value outside
their value to humans.
But why is it that ordinary citizens balk at answering questions such as how
much are you willing to pay to save the snow leopard from extinction? Economists
have found people are often unwilling to co-operate with valuation surveys.
This is because many people find that putting a price on nature is as abhorrent
as putting a price on family, friendship or freedom. It represents the further
creep of the market and economics into areas of life that have traditionally
been considered above material concerns. They do not see what their willingness
to pay has got to do with environmental policy which surely involves ethical
and cultural questions that the community as a whole must decide.
And it is this issue which is at the heart of the debate over valuation. Should
environmental protection be the subject of political debate or a technocratic
exercise undertaken by economists? Should it be a collective decision or a
collection of individual preferences? Should people have their say by naming
their price of by expressing their views?
Currently, citizens can influence governments to protect the environment by
campaigning and demonstrating as well as by voting. It is because communities
value the environment differently from developers that conflict arises in
the first place. Giving the job of assigning value to economists does not
resolve that conflict. It merely gives more influence to the values of those
who employ the economists. A system where the optimum level of environmental
protection is decided by firms and consumers responding to prices may seem
to avoid conflict but it reinforces the power of the wealthy.
Environmentalists disagree over the issue of whether the environment should
be given a price. But at the heart of that disagreement is the question of
who should be deciding. Those who favour pricing, are attempting to persuade
those in power to give more consideration to the environment by making them
see how much it is worth. The well-known British environmentalist Jonathon
Porritt argues that 'when you are talking to the people who are really in
the business of destroying the environment, you have to use concepts that
will allow them to begin to understand what we're saying'.
However, other environmentalists argue that such concessions will not change
the power structure. Larry Lohmann, in an editorial in the Ecologist, responded
to Porritt by pointing out that more environmental battles are won by local
people chanting and demonstrating in their own language and forcing leaders
to listen to them, than by people 'who allow their views to be phrased in
consultants' cost­p;benefit terms'.
Putting a price on the environment is a band-aid measure that will shift the
balance more towards environmental protection but it is a measure that reinforces
the status quo. It does this by reaffirming the market as the primary social
decision-making mechanism and emphasising the importance and priority of the
economic bottom line. It supposes that once environmental values are internalised
business can continue as usual and the environment will be protected.
A more radical conception of the problem would target these very institutions-the
freedom of the market and the profit imperative-as leading causes of environmental
degradation and inequity in modern societies. In this case the problem of valuing
the environment becomes one of finding genuinely democratic ways to ensure communities
have more say about what is produced and what is protected. And protecting the
environment means ensuring that those communities have a true understanding of
the way humans and the environment interact and a real feeling for the intrinsic
value of nature.